Highlights
- Some institutional effects of marriage will begin with the wedding, but the wedding day typically celebrates changes in commitment that have already occurred. Post This
- The societal shift that matters more than all others for how relationships impact long-term financial options may be the shift toward complexity in pathways leading to marriage. Post This
Having a long-term view supports the ability to delay gratification and invest in the future. Having a short-term view provides no reason to delay and favors immediate gratification. These points are central to understanding marriage and cohabitation, as well as how people manage money.
A recent study examines the way financial time-horizons are impacted by relationship transitions, specifically, going from being single to cohabiting and from cohabiting to being married. Barbara Fulda and Philipp Lersch conducted their study using a large data set in Australia, motivated by this question: Is there reason to be concerned about the future financial prospects of aging Australians in a world where marriage is declining and cohabitation is increasing? It’s a good question, and their study is excellent.
Their foundational assumptions were these:
- People with longer time-horizons about finances will save more for the future.
- Marriage and cohabitation have implications for time-horizons and likely impact financial behavior.
In their study, financial planning time-horizon was measured with a question that asked, “In planning your saving and spending, which of the following time periods is most important to you?” The question allowed responses ranging from “The next week,” to “More than 10 years ahead,” with many options in between. Importantly, the analyses are not about actual long-term savings. Rather, they examined what happens to this planning variable across relationship transitions, with the plausible argument that changes in financial horizons would reflect something about long-term financial outcomes.
Fulda and Lersch used a variant of what economist and sociologists call (in near worshipful tones) “fixed-effects,” which I believe to be a variant of what psychologists call “within-subjects effects.” Such analyses take advantage of datasets with over-time measurements from the same individuals; in this case, to capture changes from before to after specific transitions. While such analyses do not control for all types of selection (such as who is on this path or that path in the first place), they do control for other aspects of selection. For example, individuals vary in conscientiousness, and that could impact everything of interest here. Even without conscientiousness being measured, the fixed-effects models will control for such variance because of how people are being compared to themselves over time. This gives new meaning to the phrase, “control yourself.” (Researcher humor is the best humor.) Another example of this type of thinking can be found in a paper by Galena Rhoades, myself, and Howard Markman on changes in relationships across the transition into cohabitation (see here). I’ll come back to that.
Fulda and Lersch found that cohabiting individuals had longer financial time-horizons than singles and that financial planning horizons increased over the transition to cohabitation. There was mixed evidence of people’s financial horizons increasing further during cohabitation. In contrast, financial horizons did not increase when transitioning into marriage.
In their words, “Cohabiting individuals’ financial planning horizons thus had already increased prior to their transition into marriage.” Further, “we did not find convincing evidence for a change in the financial planning horizon before and after marriage. ...” That is, marriage “seems to contribute little to a longer financial planning horizon relative to cohabitation.” My quibble is on that point.
The authors believe the driver of the observed effects is the development (or establishment) of increased commitment during cohabitation. I think that is likely correct, but I also think the matter and meaning of the timing are more complex.
Early in the discussion of their findings, Fulda and Lersch make an important comment.
These results can be interpreted as extending previous research on the following two distinct groups of cohabiters: Those who intend to marry and those who do not. Poortman and Mills (2012) showed that the first group resembles married couples in their partnership characteristics. In this study, we expand on this finding and show that financial planning horizons of cohabiting couples’ who eventually get married remain stable as a result of their high commitment to their relationship when they transition from cohabitation into marriage.
There are different types of cohabiting unions. Some are like marriage, many are not; some become more like marriages over time, and then turn into marriages. That’s part of why cohabitation is a more ambiguous (and heterogeneous) relationship status than marriage. This is likely somewhat less true in Australia1 than in the U.S. because of a legal system that makes cohabitation more like marriage there. Here in the U.S., cohabitation contains very little information about commitment. Marriage plans, however, contain a lot of information.
Sociologist Susan Brown and colleagues have drawn attention to the fact that cohabiting couples with plans to marry tend to be, on average, a lot like married couples (see also this study). Likewise, my colleague Galena Rhoades and I have found that, among couples who end up marrying, those who started cohabiting only after having clear marriage plans (such as after engagement or who move in together only after marrying) tend to do better in marriage than those who had not decided the big question about the future beforehand (for more on those studies, see here). Deciding you want a V8 ahead of time beats “I coulda had a V8” while already holding something else. (Want to take a trip through memory lane on that? Here, knock yourself out. That’s some ancient wisdom right there.)
Furthermore, we have found cohabiting prior to engagement or marriage is associated with asymmetrically committed relationships, and that such asymmetries do not appear to change after marrying. And, as I’ve written before, asymmetrical commitment is not good.
Fulda and Lersch do not, and likely could not examine a variable that estimates the timing of when couples who married developed their mutual plans to marry. I expect that a lot of the action behind what they found lies there. In addition, while they believe that the development of commitment between partners is the most important mechanism in play, they also do not have a measure of that to analyze. Thus, the measure of a financial horizon is sort of doing double duty in their thinking.
There is nothing nearly as re-organizing for a relationship as deciding on and setting plans for a life together.
Coming back to the study noted earlier by Galena Rhoades, me, and Howard Markman, we found that commitment itself—as in dedication to one’s partner—tends to stop increasing after the transition into cohabitation. It levels off, and not at the particularly high level. Taking these points altogether, Fulda and Lersch do not have a way to look at the actual timing of changes in interpersonal commitment, nor can they look at the exact timing of when mutual plans for marriage develop. It would be especially interesting to be able to look at their research question with access to such measures.
To be clear, I have little doubt that financial planning can change with cohabitation. However, I suspect that Fulda and Lersch’s cohabitation-transition effects are likely, and largely, a proxy for the effect of developing marriage plans before cohabiting or while cohabiting. Either way, the effects Fulda and Lersch are attributing solely to cohabitation seem mostly to be marriage effects occurring before marriage. There is nothing nearly as re-organizing for a relationship as deciding on and setting plans for a life together.
Important Details (for the truly committed)
Skip ahead if you are not interested in nuances.
First, consider this point the authors make about fixed-effects:
By conducting longitudinal analyses, our results indicated that individuals who marry after having cohabited were a selective, more future-oriented group among all cohabiting individuals. Once this selection was controlled for in the fixed effects estimation, the financial planning horizon was not significantly different between cohabiting and married individuals.
While that may sound like they were controlling away marriage effects, I believe they are properly stating what their data show: that those who eventually married had longer financial time-horizons all along. This is one of the great advantages of having over-time measures within individuals. It allows you to know the path someone was already on before the event of interest happened.
Second, researchers routinely make consequential decisions that can impact their conclusions. Fulda and Lersch excluded 38% of the singles in their starting data set because they had cohabited with someone prior to the first wave in the sample.2 While this decision makes sense given their focus on first transitions into cohabitation or marriage, the decision excludes those who are or will become serial cohabiters. In the U.S., serial cohabitation tends to be a higher-risk pathway when it comes to marriage and family stability, and serial cohabitation is also associated with greater disadvantage.3 Hence, Fulda and Lersch’s decision may lower generalizability of their findings in a couple of important ways.
Third, there is an important limitation of this study: they were not examining the long-term financial outcomes of people who have traveled varying pathways, such as for those who had cohabited with plans to marry, married, and remained together or divorced, or those who had lived together, developed plans for marriage while doing so, and remained together or divorced, or those who cohabited and never married. I didn’t even work into that sentence the mind-numbing complexity of the timing of children, or with whom one has those children. Fulda and Lersch’s study is an attempt to glimpse some answer to a broader question, but the question itself is difficult to answer because of all the possible pathways. The societal shift that matters more than all others for how relationships impact long-term financial options may be the shift toward so much complexity in the pathways leading up to marriage.
Cohabitation, Marriage, and Time Horizons
I believe marriage effects start long before a couple walks down the aisle. Similar effects can occur without marriage if a mutual and high level of commitment emerges. However, marriage remains the strongest cultural signal encoding such a commitment.4 Sure, some institutional effects of marriage will begin with the wedding, but the wedding day typically celebrates changes in commitment that have already occurred.
Fulda and Lersch concluded that concerns about the long-term financial prospects of Australians may be overblown. Bolstering this conclusion is the fact that the laws and mores in Australia make cohabitation a near functional equivalent to marriage. I do believe it is a different deal there compared to the United States. However, there are reasons to think that long-term implications of cohabitation versus marriage may still be substantial for children, even in societies where the two statuses have become close in legal equivalence. This fact was recently documented by Brad Wilcox and Laurie DeRose with a multi-national data set.5
Marriage may eventually lose its status as the strongest signal of commitment to “us with a future,” but I do not think that day has yet arrived. Until marriage disappears, marriage effects will start before marriage.
Scott M. Stanley is a research professor at the University of Denver and fellow of the Institute for Family Studies.
1. As an aside, the first scholar to nail the issue of the fundamental ambiguity of cohabitation was Jo Lindsay—an Australian research doing a qualitative study on cohabitation first published in 2000 based on interviews in the early 90s.
2. It seems possible from their description that they excluded those with prior cohabitation history from the cohabitation transition analyses but not from the transition to marriage analyses. If so, I might also be concerned about this decision in terms of potential impact on their findings.
3. This becomes of added importance when considering the ways that poverty warps the ability to make present decisions based on the future. Poverty, of course, would deeply impact both financial and relationship behavior, and push people toward a shortened sense of a future. Sociologists such as Kathryn Edin, Sharon Sassler, Wendy Manning, and Pamela Smock have compellingly argued that people make very different relationship bets if they are deeply impacted by poverty and disadvantage. If you do not have much of a sense of a bright future, uncertainty dissuades you from setting anything aside. Of course, so does the fact of not really having much of anything to set aside, even if you wanted to do so.
4. For more on the matter of signals of commitment, I recommend: Rowthorn, R. (2002). Marriage as a signal. In A. W. Dnes and R. Rowthorn (Eds.), The Law and Economics of Marriage and Divorce (pp. 132 - 156). New York: Cambridge University Press.; Nock, S.L. (2009). The Growing Importance of Marriage in America. In H. E. Peters and C. M. Kamp Dush (Eds.), Marriage and Family: Perspectives and Complexities (pp. 302-324). New York: Columbia University Press.; Stanley, S. M., Rhoades, G. K., & Whitton, S. W. (2010). Commitment: Functions, formation, and the securing of romantic attachment. Journal of Family Theory and Review, 2, 243-257.
5. Wilcox and DeRose found a consistent and seemingly large difference in family stability for children of married versus cohabiting couples in many European countries; countries where cohabitation with children has legal characteristics similar to marriage. The larger story here is constantly unfolding into the future, but such findings suggest that marriage still represents a different commitment to the future than cohabitation.